Monday, April 21, 2014

State Division of labour in Traditional and Modern East Africa Society.

Introduction
Because of the large amount of labor saved by giving workers specialized tasks in Industrial Revolution era, classical economists such as Adam Smith and mechanical engineers such as Charles Babbage were proponents of division of labor. Also, having workers perform single or limited tasks eliminated the long training period required to train craftsmen, who were replaced with lesser paid but more productive unskilled workers. Historically, an increasingly complex division of labor is associated with the growth of total output and trade, the rise of capitalism, and of the complexity of industrialized processes. 

The concept and implementation of division of labor has been observed in ancient Sumerian (Mesopotamian) culture, where assignment of jobs in some cities coincided with an increase in trade and economic interdependence. In addition to trade and economic interdependence, division of labor generally increases both producer and individual worker productivity. In contrast to division of labor, division of work refers to the division of a large task, contract, or project into smaller task each with a separate schedule within the overall project schedule. (Durkheim, Emile 1997)

Definition of key terms;
The division of labor is the specialization of Labor economics who perform specific tasks and roles in different aspects of social lives (Wadeson, N. 2013)
Division of labor an approach to the completion of a complex task which involves breaking the task into a number of simpler tasks and assigning these tasks to specialists who generally perform only their assigned task (Robert M. Solow and Jean-Philippe Touffut 2010)

Division of labor, instead, refers to the allocation of tasks to individuals or organizations according to the skills and or equipment those people or organizations possess. Often division of labor and division of work are both part of the economic activity within an industrial nation or organization (Durkheim, Emile 1997)

The small, roving band of hunter-gatherers, the Pygmies the Hadza of Tanzania, was, perhaps, the most egalitarian of traditional African societies. Isolated, continually on the move, with the minimum of structure, the band of hunters had a continually fluctuating membership, the mothers with little children stay at home doing domestic works and caring for the little child of one year to five years, while five up to fifteen years old they are for keeping animals, above fifteen up to twenty five they are engaging in hunting and gathering with their fathers, while adult men are to settle community disputes hence adult women are to prepare young ladies for coming marriage.

Nomadism applied in varying degrees to the pastoralists the Turkana of Kenya, exhibit considerable mobility and flux in the composition of their settlements and camps; at the other end, the Nandi of Kenya and the Gogo of Tanzania are more sedentary and interested in agriculture. In fact, there is a pattern in the movements of all pastoralists, dictated as it is by the availability of water and grazing. In Ugogo (Tanzania) sons-in-law are required by custom to help build for their father-in-law, In return, the father-in-law provides an ox which will be slaughtered in the compound as a feast for the living and a sacrifice to the dead. 

It is a fact, too, that pastoralists carry out a fair amount of cultivation, since all the three have the same division of labor, the children below five years stay at home with pregnant mothers helping in domestic activities, six to twelve years they are keeping cattle’s with some of adults, fourteen to forty years old they are participating in agriculture and social protections, the remained adults are to settle disputes.  

Pastoralism has always been precarious and conducted in remote and marginal areas. Many pastoralist peoples exploited neighboring groups of cultivators or classes of cultivator-serfs, denying them full rights of membership of their society, particularly the right to own cattle. The inequality inherent in this situation has especially tragic consequences in countries with cattle-owning aristocracies such as Rwanda and Burundi societies(Hill, Lisa 2004).

In general, however, pastoralist societies were more egalitarian than chieftain societies, and stratification was one of their most conspicuous features. The whole society was divided into a greater or lesser number of age-sets or generation-sets, each of which was composed of a number of age groups or batches of individuals initiated annually. Among some peoples, The Jie of Uganda, on the other hand, had only two generation sets, each composed of five age sets with a depth of five or six years, and this situation was comparable to that of the Masai of Kenya in Tanzania with their twofold division of warrior and elder.

Ages-sets and generation-sets possessed public duties. The elders presided over society as a whole, and the junior adults or warriors acted as a disciplinary force. This status of warrior was a means of prolonging adolescence socially in a polygamous society where there was necessarily a wide disparity in the age for marriage. Girls were married young, men married late, thus permitting a greater number of men to be polygamous. 

However, adolescent rebelliousness had to be canalized for the good of society, and the chagrin of young men at losing their sweethearts to old men had to be softened. The warrior peer-group had all these functions. It acted as a kind of military or police force, with its own common living, its own collective morality and allegiance. In the modern world, of course, it becomes progressively difficult to maintain such an institution in existence. Not only does school education threaten this system, but close administration makes it virtually impossible for the warrior-youths to fulfill their social role.

The Luo of Kenya and northern Tanzania offer us an example of this kind of situation. In all of these kinds of society, stratified, segmentary, atomized, government was traditionally at a minimum, and social control was exercised very largely through the blood-feud. Sanctions consisted in the warriors taking revenge on behalf of their clan or settlement and exacting compensation for injuries done. 

Guilt was deemed to be collective and the obligation to punish or take revenge was also strictly collective. Most of these societies evolved a clan of priest-chiefs or prophets who exercised important reconciliatory functions between warring clans and groups. The priest-chief exercised no permanent office, and had no administrative powers. He was summoned ad hoc to deal with a given situation and to give expression to the will of disputing social groups to bury their differences. 

Accord was symbolized and affected usually in a sacrificial feast. Some societies, like that of the Masai, had a paramount religious leader, the head of the clan of priest-chiefs, who possessed important prophetic functions. His task was especially to give unity and direction to the action of the whole tribe in moments of crisis, war, famine and so on hence eighteen to forty five were to deal those crisis, With political and strategically ability, such a prophet could exercise considerable influence over his people.

It appears, therefore, that in these types of society decision making took place at a reasonably low social level. However, there were recognized norms of behavior to which people were expected to conform and to which appeal was made when conflicts arose. The role of the priest-chiefs shows this. Moreover, and this is demonstrated by the role of the prophet paramount, such norms did not necessarily apply to alien peoples. 

The pastoralist societies offer us a flagrant example of the way in which relationships between ethnic groups were sometimes not subject to any recognized norms. Conflicts between tribesmen could be resolved according to precedent, and on account of the will of the conflicting parties to be reconciled to each other. Conflicts between ethnic groups were implacable. The herds of cattle possessed by neighboring tribes were there to be plundered; their owners had no rights. One's own tribesmen, on the other hand, had very strict rights over his herds, and compensation for theft could be demanded and enforced.

The pastoralist societies, as already indicated, were not so bound by familial ties as many sedentary peoples. Grazing livestock over vast distances required an understanding between individual stock-owners that neither would molest the other, and that watering and grazing rights would be respected. Associations between individuals based on the magical blood-pact, or on the exchange of stock, afforded the individual a form of security in his movement over vast distances, far away from kinsmen and clansmen. Such pacts or bonds were among the most sacred and inviolable in traditional Africa.

Conclusion;
The division of labor has its complementary ways of division according to various tribes and other groups in East Africa as it has some of the very difficult ways of division of labor but in fact it is good just because it provides an emphasis to the young generations on how to keep busy working hard due to fact that they are preparing their own lives, hence societies has to be fulfilled by people who are experts.



References;
Hill, Lisa (2004). Adam Smith, Adam Ferguson and the Division of Labour. University of
Adelaide
Emile Durkheim, (1893) seminal work, (De La Division Du Travail Social The Division of Labor in Society),"dedicated himself to the establishment of sociology as a legitimate and respected science and as an instrument of rational social action." Alpert, Harry. "Emile Durkheim: A Perspective and Appreciation." American Sociological Review  JSTOR. Web. 6 April2014.
Merton, Robert K. (1994), Durkheim's Division of Labor in Society, Oxford University Printing
Press.
Cowan, Tyler (2008). "Division of labor". The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks,
CA: SAGE Cato Institute.
F. Froebel, F., J. Heinrichs and O. Krey,(1991) The New International Division of Labor,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.    





 Written By AUSI CHIWAMBO (2014)-Teofilo Kisanji University

No comments:

Post a Comment